Rethinking Mercantilism: Political Economy, the British Empire, and the Atlantic World in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries
Author(s): Steve Pincus
Reviewed work(s):
Source: The William and Mary Quarterly, Vol. 69, No. 1 (January 2012), pp. 3-34
Published by: Omohundro Institute of Early American History and Culture
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.5309/willmaryquar.69.1.0003 .
Accessed: 06/09/2012 12:18
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp .
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
…show more content…
Historians, social scientists, and literary critics have by and large accepted Smith’s notion that there was an early modern period of mercantilist consensus. Most of those scholars have associated this view, at least in part, with the notion that everyone who mattered believed that trade was a zero-sum game. They have assumed that because land and the raw materials derived from it were the ultimate measure of wealth in the early modern period, wealth was necessarily finite. Policy makers operating under these assumptions, we are frequently told, subordinated the interests of the periphery to the imperatives of the metropolitan core. However, these assumptions, at least about seventeenth- and eighteenth-century England, are untenable. That realization warrants rethinking the origins and contours of British imperial rule and the structure of the Atlantic world.
Adam Smith’s powerful and stadial view of European commercial development stimulated the thinking of classical economists. John Ramsay
McCulloch, James Mill, David Ricardo, Nassau Senior, and a host of others castigated the evils of the mercantile system. But it was in the later nineteenth and early twentieth centuries that scholars in history, imperial
history,
The value of Wealth of Nations did not lie on the presented ideas being original, but it rested on the brilliant way in which Smith organized and fitted the different ideas from different thinkers into one massive masterpiece – like a completed jigsaw puzzle, his work has been described as a comprehensive landscape of economics . His work and contribution to the world of economics made him the ‘Father of Economics’ and inspired many economists after him such as David Ricardo and Thomas Malthus.
In 1607 the British began to colonize North America. Britain enforce certain rules, such as the colonies could only trade with its mother country, to make sure that it was the only country benefiting for the colonies. However there was a period of Salutary Neglect. “Salutary neglect was Britain's unofficial policy to relax the enforcement of strict regulations, particularly trade laws, imposed on the American colonies late in the seventeenth and early in the eighteenth centuries” (Henretta). In this duration of time the colonies began to establish their own trade routes, politics, and procedures which helped form their sense of nationalism.
within a year. Fear of more violence led the British to establish a western limit
1.) Mercantilism controlled the trade of the colonies affecting their political and economical development. This system was in effect throughout The 1500's to the 1700's where the mother country controlled the industry and trade of other, weaker settlements. It restricted trade to anywhere except Europe. Both Europe and the colonies benefited in some ways.
One huge figure that driven to the colonists’ discontent is Mercantilism. Mercantilism was the thought that colonies were an vital source of crude materials. A parcel of the crude materials were taken from America and sent to Britain to offer assistance the mother nation fabricate products to exchange with other nations. It was thought that by expanding trades and collecting valuable metals in return, that it would progress the national riches and control.
Published in 2016, this secondary source was written using a variety of references by Thomas Brinkerhoff, a Ph.D. student studying Colonial Latin America and Global Empires and Imperial Legacies at the esteemed University of Pennsylvania. Brinkerhoff’s academic credibility
Economics in the seventeenth and eighteenth century were dominated by the idea of mercantilism. Mercantilism depended on the cooperation between colony and mother country in the shipping and production of raw materials. Domestic industry increased employment, expanded commercial activity within the country and decreased France's dependence on foreign trade. The success of a Mercantile system relied on the government, participating merchants, even nobility and the working class, all had effects on the success of the French economy.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR,
Mercantilism is an economic theory where a nation's strength comes from building up gold supplies and expanding its trade. Britain formed the American colonies so that they could increase their gold stores. They wanted raw supplies to make into products to sell and make money. They wanted America to pay taxes so that Britain could make money. America used the theory in that they thought they ought to, in order to be strong expand their trade beyond Britain. Countries like Belgium, and France wanted to also increase their trade, and expand it to trading with America. They also wanted to increase their gold stores by trading with America. Britain however did not want America to trade with France and Belgium and the Netherlands because they
The English colonies in North America were slowly separating themselves from the crown. It starts with radical kings in Europe who cause so much disruption that a civil war occurs. The colonies worked together to fend for themselves and survived quite well without the crown and Parliament watching over them. England was not aware of it but every little thing they did to try reasserting command over the colonies only pushed them farther away. If England had always kept a firm hand on the colonies, we would be speaking proper English and marveling at our queen in the twenty-first century.
The year 1607 brought England into the "New World" with its first permanent settlement at Jamestown, and the following years would bring more American colonies to the British Empire. When sending people into the new land, the English planned to use a mercantilist policy and fully use the colonies for their resources. The colonist's creation of the proverb "Mother countries exist for the benefit of their colonies" is sufficient because England's original intentions of mercantilism soon disappeared after their entrance into this new world. The reason for the decline in their motives can be traced to many occurrences, most notably benign neglect of the colonies and internal English conflicts. In many cases, the mother
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
Mercantilism Mercantilism is the economic theory that a nation's prosperity depends on its supply of gold and silver; that the total volume of trade is unchangeable. This theory suggests that the government should play an active role in the economy by encouraging exports and discouraging imports, especially through the use of tariffs. Spain and England used the mercantile system to benefit the mother countries. The mercantile system had special regulations, which usually extracted some sort of reaction from the colonies. If necessary, the policies would be changed to better suit the mother country.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.