Suppose you are considering becoming a professional athlete. Whilst a pro athlete can expect to make a lot of money when they're young, they may struggle to find gainful employment later in life. If you decide against going pro, you can expect a much steadier income, though perhaps not quite as lucrative at 21. Which will you choose?!? Let's set this up formally. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Suppose that you live for two periods, t = 1,2. If you go pro, in t=1, you will earn Y, which is more than what you would earn in /=1 if you do not go pro, YP; i.e. YP> ymp However, in period 1=2, as a pro you will earn zero: Y = 0. By contrast, Y > 0. Being a pro athlete makes you a prominent public figure. In period t=1, you have to pay security guards a fixed amount S to keep you safe from the mob of fans who no doubt follow your every insta. 2. Once your professional career is over, you are quickly forgotten, so you don't have to spend anything on security in t=2 (Sad ). Non-pros have no such problems; they do not pay S' in t=1 or t=2. You have well-behaved preferences (you like more consumption, and you have decreasing marginal utility in consumption in both periods) You can borrow and lend at the rate r an asset b. You are selfish! No bequeathments from past generations, and you pass on nothing. First suppose that you do not go pro 1. Write down the dynamic budget constraint Derive the intertemporal budget constraint 3. Show graphically the budget constraint and the optimal consumption point in period 1 and 2. Make sure this is big; you're going to need to draw more onto it later!
Suppose you are considering becoming a professional athlete. Whilst a pro athlete can expect to make a lot of money when they're young, they may struggle to find gainful employment later in life. If you decide against going pro, you can expect a much steadier income, though perhaps not quite as lucrative at 21. Which will you choose?!? Let's set this up formally. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Suppose that you live for two periods, t = 1,2. If you go pro, in t=1, you will earn Y, which is more than what you would earn in /=1 if you do not go pro, YP; i.e. YP> ymp However, in period 1=2, as a pro you will earn zero: Y = 0. By contrast, Y > 0. Being a pro athlete makes you a prominent public figure. In period t=1, you have to pay security guards a fixed amount S to keep you safe from the mob of fans who no doubt follow your every insta. 2. Once your professional career is over, you are quickly forgotten, so you don't have to spend anything on security in t=2 (Sad ). Non-pros have no such problems; they do not pay S' in t=1 or t=2. You have well-behaved preferences (you like more consumption, and you have decreasing marginal utility in consumption in both periods) You can borrow and lend at the rate r an asset b. You are selfish! No bequeathments from past generations, and you pass on nothing. First suppose that you do not go pro 1. Write down the dynamic budget constraint Derive the intertemporal budget constraint 3. Show graphically the budget constraint and the optimal consumption point in period 1 and 2. Make sure this is big; you're going to need to draw more onto it later!
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Related questions
Question
Any help with this would be appreciated
Expert Solution
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
This is a popular solution!
Trending now
This is a popular solution!
Step by step
Solved in 3 steps with 1 images
Knowledge Booster
Learn more about
Need a deep-dive on the concept behind this application? Look no further. Learn more about this topic, economics and related others by exploring similar questions and additional content below.Recommended textbooks for you
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education