ENGR.ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
14th Edition
ISBN: 9780190931919
Author: NEWNAN
Publisher: Oxford University Press
expand_more
expand_more
format_list_bulleted
Question
Katie’s preferences for consumption and leisure can be expressed as
U(C, L) = (C – 80) x (L – 40)
This utility function implies that Katie’s
- Graph Katie’s budget line.
- What is Katie’s marginal rate of substitution when L = 70 and she is on her budget line?
- What is Katie’s reservation wage?
- Find Katie’s optimal amount of consumption and leisure.
Expert Solution
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
This is a popular solution
Trending nowThis is a popular solution!
Step by stepSolved in 4 steps
Follow-up Questions
Read through expert solutions to related follow-up questions below.
Follow-up Question
- Find Katie’s optimal amount of consumption and leisure.
Solution
by Bartleby Expert
Follow-up Questions
Read through expert solutions to related follow-up questions below.
Follow-up Question
- Find Katie’s optimal amount of consumption and leisure.
Solution
by Bartleby Expert
Knowledge Booster
Similar questions
- Rebecca's wage is $10 per hour, and she can work up to 60 hours per week. The table and the budget constraint graph show the trade-off that she faces between income and leisure in one week of potential work at this wage. Her manager raises her wage to $15 per hour. Change the graph below to illustrate her new income-leisure budget constraint. The line and the individual endpoints are movable. Assume that nothing else changes. Hours Leisure time Income ($) (hours) worked at $10/hour 0 200 400 600 0 20 40 60 60 40 20 0 Income ($) 1000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 Leisure (hours)arrow_forwardConsider a single mother with the utility function U = 2/3 log(x) + 1/3 log(), where x is consumption and is leisure. The mother can work up to 100 hours per month. Any of the 100 hours that are not worked are leisure hours. She earns a wage of $10 per hour and pays no taxes. The consumption price is normalized to $1. To be able to work, she has to incur a child care cost of $5 for every hour worked. a. Suppose that there is no tax and welfare benefits. How many hours will she work and what will be her consumption level? Draw the graph depicting her budget set with consumption on the vertical axis and leisure on the horizontal axis. b. Suppose that the government introduces a negative income tax (NIT) that guarantees an income of $200 per month. The benefit is taken away one for one as earnings increase. Draw the new budget set. Compute the new number of hours worked and consumption level. Has consumption increased and is the mother better off? Why or why not? c. Now…arrow_forwardQ3. Consider a utility function with one consumption good q1 and one type of leisure q2 c) Show mathematically and diagrammatically the decomposition of totaleffect.arrow_forward
- just subparts a, b and c pleasearrow_forwardConsider an individual whose utility function is U(C, R) = 2C - (4 - R) 2 where R is the amount of leisure the consumer experiences per day. Suppose that the individual normally sleeps T hours a day, and they can spend the remaining hours between work and leisure. The individual receives an hourly wage of w > 0 and has also an income of Y > 0 a day from non - labour sources. The price of consumption goods is p per unit.arrow_forward4. Steve's utility funetion over leisure and consumption is given by u(L,Y) = min (3L, Y). Wage rate is w and the price of the composite consumption good is p = 1. (a) Suppose w = 5. Find the optimal leisure - consumption combination. What is the amount of hours worked? (b) Suppose the overtime law is passed so that every worker needs to be paid 1.5 times their current wage for hours worked beyond the first 8 hours. Will this law induce Steve to work more hours? If so, how many? If not, explain.arrow_forward
- A. Consider a consumer whose preferences can be represented by Cobb-Douglas utility function u(x₁, x₂) = xx where ₁ and 2 are the quantities of good 1 and good 2 she consumes. Let p₁ and p2 be the prices of good 1 and good 2 and let m denote her income. 1. Derive the consumer's Marshallian demand functions. 2. Derive the consumer's Hicksian demand functions. 3. Derive the consumer's expenditure function. 4. Let m = 20, P₁ = 2, and p2 = 1. Suppose that the price of good 1 drops to p₁ = 1. Find the following (a) Compensating variation (CV) (b) Equivalent variation (EV) (c) Change in consumer surplus (ACS) (d) Compare CV, ACS, and EV. 5. Let m = 120, P₁ = 1, and p2 = 1. Suppose that the price of good 1 increases to P₁ = 2. Find the following (a) Compensating variation (CV) (b) Equivalent variation (EV) (c) Change in consumer surplus (ACS) (d) Compare CV, ACS, and EV.arrow_forwardConsider two individuals, Carole and Mo, who each have a job opportunity that pays a wage of $20 per hour and allows them to choose the number of hours per week they'd like to work. Carole has stronger preferences for leisure than Mo. Ultimately, both Carole and Mo choose to work more than zero hours per week. Draw (and upload) one graph that includes: • Carole and Mo's income-leisure constraint • Carole's utility-maximizing indifference curve (Uc) and choice of leisure hours (Lc) • Mo's utility-maximizing indifference curve (UM) and choice of leisure hours (LM) [Note: There are multiple, though similar, ways to draw this graph. Focus on ensuring that the constraint, indifference curves and hours worked align with the information provided above.]arrow_forwardThe utility of Amanda for leisure (L) and income (Y) is U = LY. The price of income is 1. If Amanda uses her spare L hours a day, (24 - L) hours will be labored. Since wages are w, the daily income is (24 - L). If the wages are positive, show that the optimal number of leisure hours that Amanda will use will always be the same. How much leisure time does Amanda demand and how much work time do she want to provide?arrow_forward
- Consider a worker who consumes one good and has a preference for leisure. She maximizes the utility function u(x, L) = xL, where a represents consumption of the good and L represents leisure. Suppose that this worker can choose any L € [0, 1], and receives income w(1 – L); w represents the wage rate. Let p denote the price of the consumption good. In addition to her wage income, the worker also has a fixed income of y ≥ 0. (a) Write down the utility maximization problem for this consumer. Solution: The problem is max x L s.t. px ≤w(1 L) + y. x>0, LE [0,1] The budget constraint may also be written with equality since preferences are monotone. (b) Find the Marshallian demands for the consumption good and leisure. Solution: Using FOCs will find the maximum since preferences are Cobb-Douglas (and therefore convex). Dividing the FOCs L= Xp and x = Xw gives wL = px. Substituting into the budget constraint and checking the restriction L = [0, 1], we get and x(p, w, y) L(p, w, y) = = = 1 w+y…arrow_forwardKevin has a wage income of $10,000 in the present and $15,000 in the future. His utility is given as U = min (4cp, 5cf), where cp denotes consumption today and cf consumption in the future. The relevant interest rate is 10%. a. If the interest rate were to increase to 15 percent,would Kevin be better off or worse off? Explain. b. Find two measures to indicate how much better off or worse off Kevin is as a result of the increase in interest rates. Explain.arrow_forward2nd attempt See Hint A consumer faces a tradeoff between labor (L) and leisure (R). She consumes a composite good (C). When the consumer works, she earns an hourly wage of $15.00, and she spends a maximum of 24 hours on labor and leisure, but she chooses to work 10.00 hours. Whatever time she does not spend working, she spends on leisure. She starts with an initial endowment of 11.00 units of the composite good, which she can buy and sell freely at a market price of $4.00. Given this information, what is the consumer's real wage? $ 194arrow_forward
arrow_back_ios
SEE MORE QUESTIONS
arrow_forward_ios
Recommended textbooks for you
- Principles of Economics (12th Edition)EconomicsISBN:9780134078779Author:Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. OsterPublisher:PEARSONEngineering Economy (17th Edition)EconomicsISBN:9780134870069Author:William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick KoellingPublisher:PEARSON
- Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)EconomicsISBN:9781305585126Author:N. Gregory MankiwPublisher:Cengage LearningManagerial Economics: A Problem Solving ApproachEconomicsISBN:9781337106665Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike ShorPublisher:Cengage LearningManagerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-...EconomicsISBN:9781259290619Author:Michael Baye, Jeff PrincePublisher:McGraw-Hill Education
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:9780134078779
Author:Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:9780134870069
Author:William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:9781305585126
Author:N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:9781337106665
Author:Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-...
Economics
ISBN:9781259290619
Author:Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:McGraw-Hill Education