A guilty Defendant appears in court and can decide whether to plead guilty (G) or innocent (I). The Prosecutor can advocate for a harsh (H) or a lenient (L) sentence. The judge's response is mechanical, and she will sentence the Defendant to 1, 2, or 3 years of jail if the outcome is (G, L), (G, H), or (I, H), respectively. The judge will acquit the Defendant if the outcome is (I, L). Studies have found that punishments tend to be affected by the judge's or prosecutor's mood. We account for this in our model by saying that the Prosecutor's mood is exogenously and randomly determined to be good or bad. If the Prosecutor's mood is good, he wants to match the Defendant's action (playing H when the Defendant plays G and L when they play I) because the Prosecutor is uncertain whether the Defendant is actually guilty. If the Prosecutor's mood is bad, he simply wants to the Defendant to go to jail for as long as possible. The Prosecutor knows his own mood, but the Defendant does not know his mood. The utilities that come from these payoffs are as follows: G I H -2,1 -3,0 L -1,0 0,1 Good Mood G I H -2,2 -3,3 L -1,1 0,0 Bad Mood Find all Bayesian Nash equilibria, given that the probability of the pros- ecutor being in a good mood is 2/3.
A guilty Defendant appears in court and can decide whether to plead guilty (G) or innocent (I). The Prosecutor can advocate for a harsh (H) or a lenient (L) sentence. The judge's response is mechanical, and she will sentence the Defendant to 1, 2, or 3 years of jail if the outcome is (G, L), (G, H), or (I, H), respectively. The judge will acquit the Defendant if the outcome is (I, L). Studies have found that punishments tend to be affected by the judge's or prosecutor's mood. We account for this in our model by saying that the Prosecutor's mood is exogenously and randomly determined to be good or bad. If the Prosecutor's mood is good, he wants to match the Defendant's action (playing H when the Defendant plays G and L when they play I) because the Prosecutor is uncertain whether the Defendant is actually guilty. If the Prosecutor's mood is bad, he simply wants to the Defendant to go to jail for as long as possible. The Prosecutor knows his own mood, but the Defendant does not know his mood. The utilities that come from these payoffs are as follows: G I H -2,1 -3,0 L -1,0 0,1 Good Mood G I H -2,2 -3,3 L -1,1 0,0 Bad Mood Find all Bayesian Nash equilibria, given that the probability of the pros- ecutor being in a good mood is 2/3.
Chapter1: Making Economics Decisions
Section: Chapter Questions
Problem 1QTC
Related questions
Question
Please no written by hand and no emage
Expert Solution
This question has been solved!
Explore an expertly crafted, step-by-step solution for a thorough understanding of key concepts.
Step by step
Solved in 4 steps with 90 images
Recommended textbooks for you
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (12th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134078779
Author:
Karl E. Case, Ray C. Fair, Sharon E. Oster
Publisher:
PEARSON
Engineering Economy (17th Edition)
Economics
ISBN:
9780134870069
Author:
William G. Sullivan, Elin M. Wicks, C. Patrick Koelling
Publisher:
PEARSON
Principles of Economics (MindTap Course List)
Economics
ISBN:
9781305585126
Author:
N. Gregory Mankiw
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach
Economics
ISBN:
9781337106665
Author:
Luke M. Froeb, Brian T. McCann, Michael R. Ward, Mike Shor
Publisher:
Cengage Learning
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy (Mcgraw-…
Economics
ISBN:
9781259290619
Author:
Michael Baye, Jeff Prince
Publisher:
McGraw-Hill Education